The Economics of the Moral Compass
Why do
some people consider it a profound moral wrong for government or
individuals to legally recognize a gay or lesbian marriage while
others feel, just as profoundly, that to deny the legal right and
benefits of traditional marriage to a deeply-committed gay or lesbian
couple is a violation of basic human rights, simple human decency,
and a moral wrong? How is it that we can come to such
diametrically opposed answers to so many of the same moral questions?
When we describe something as being “morally wrong,” exactly who
(or what) is being wronged? Is a path through the minefield of the
deeply-held beliefs of our fellow human beings even possible? My
intent is not to tell anyone what to think, but I do intend to
present some ways of thinking about the problems and specific
elements that must be part of whatever answers we may come to.
Two
modern sciences are especially relevant in trying to answer the
questions posed above, both of which have roots that arguably go back
to the Ancient Greeks and, during the Enlightenment, were called
moral philosophy and
political economy. In hindsight, it is not a coincidence that
the Scottish philosopher, Adam Smith, wrote the seminal works that
essentially founded the disciplines that today we call moral
psychology and economics, The Theory of Moral Sentiments in
1759 and An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations in 1776. Just how tightly intertwined moral issues are
with economic issues in modern societies is easily seen in the annual
battle over the federal budget in the U.S. where economic and
budgetary priorities are often dictated by the moral/ethical
priorities of differing constituencies or pressure groups. The issue
of sex education in public schools is a good example; do we spend the
money on "abstinence only" programs or do we spend it on
programs that aim to prevent unwanted teen pregnancies and the spread
of STDs. Where we, both individually and collectively, come down on
that one is determined largely by our moral reasoning around human
sexuality. I will get to such issues in time, but to make my point, I
must first discuss a sub-field of both economics (a social science)
and psychology (a behavioral science) that has only been around since
the 1960s called behavioral economics.
Economists
going back to Adam Smith assumed that economic actors–business
owners, consumers, investors, etc.–were rational actors pursuing
their individual aims in the objectively most efficient way possible.
Subsequent generations of economists made this assumption explicit by
defining "man" in a strictly economic context as an agent
that seeks only to maximize his store of wealth by the most effective
and rational means possible. As national economies grew and became
ever more inter-connected throughout the 19th century, the amount of
economic data available to economists grew by leaps and bounds. In
parallel with this, advanced analytic mathematical techniques were
developed that allowed the creation of mathematical models of
economic systems where all actors–buyers, sellers, producers,
suppliers, etc.–have the same information as the other parties and,
in that context, act rationally in pursuit of their individual ends.
The quality or robustness of any mathematical model of a system,
whether of the gravitationally-bound Earth-Moon system, the climate,
or an economy is judged by comparing the performance of the model
against what has happened in the past, will happen in the future, in
controlled experiments, or a combination of all of these. As
economists in the first half of the 20th century applied ever more
sophisticated models to the wealth of economic data available to
them, the abstractions of human beings as rational actors grew
increasingly untenable as their models often diverged from what it
seems “economic actors” actually do in the real world.
Of the
nations that fought on either side in World War II, not only was the
United States the only one come out of it with their economy intact,
but it flourished beyond anyone's most optimistic imaginings in the
years and decades afterwards. In this economic boom, the number of
roughly equivalent types of consumer goods, e.g. vacuums, toasters,
televisions, radios, automobiles, etc., that people could choose from
grew faster than consumers could keep up with. It was essential that
manufacturers and retailers—and the advertising and marketing firms
they retained—understood how consumers think and how best to pitch
their products so consumers would choose theirs over the available
alternatives. Over the last 50+ years, advertising and marketing
firms have taken advantage of insights into human decision-making and
cognition from the behavioral sciences.
One
reason the rational actor model fails is that most of our decisions,
even the big ones, like one’s college major or who to marry1,
are the result of a heuristic process, such as common sense, rules of
thumb, and educated guesses in which our emotions, rather than any
sort of rational analysis. Usually, heuristic processes are not
rationally coherent, but they do have the advantage of a much lower
cognitive load—and are often the most emotionally palatable in that
moment. In other cases, as shown in a study published in the Journal
of Consumer Research in 20002,
the authors describe an experiment that sought to find out if
customers’ choices of “free” beer samples in a college town
brewpub were influenced by others in their party. In the first
variation of the experiment (I’ll call it “A”), customers
verbally indicated their choices within the hearing of others at the
table. Then, after having a chance to taste their selection, they
were presented with a card asking them what their selection was and
what they thought of it. In the next variation (“B”), customers
indicated their order on a card—essentially a secret ballot, then,
just as in the first iteration, customers were asked to rate their
enjoyment of their choice.
When the
results of both variations of the experiment were tallied,
researchers found that when everyone else at the table could hear
their order, few, if any, chose the same beer as any of the others.
However, in the “secret ballot” variation, there was a great deal
more clustering of customers choices. When the scientists looked at
customers’ post-tasting feedback, for round “A” they found that
those whose orders were among the last to be taken were less
enthusiastic with their “choice.” In round B, when each customer
was unaware of what others ordered they had a much higher opinion of
their choice. The researchers noted that these findings were exactly
what one would expect to find when behaviors and choices are
dominated by a need for uniquenessi,
and in this context is called “Consumers' Need for Uniqueness
(CNFU)”—and yes, in the world of consumer research it really is a
“thing.”ii
Our culture places a high value on individual uniqueness and
independence of mind and in social situations—especially when we
are hoping to impress others with our independence of mind—this
need can often outweigh our own preferences.
Some
critics have made the accusation that much of the recent research in
the cognitive and behavioral sciences—and by extension, the
researchers—is aiding and abetting in the cynical—I’ll be
blunt—manipulation of consumer-citizensiii
(i.e. us), especially in the application of such research to
the field of marketing.iv
While I personally do not subscribe to such conspiracy theories,
researchers in social psychology and behavioral economics are
often attached to universities’ schools of Management and/or
Business, but I think Hanlon's razor3
more than adequately accounts for this. It is also worth mentioning
that a substantial share of current research—and thus
researchers—are focused on helping professionals of all kinds, as
well as consumer-citizens, make better decisions by pointing out the
blind spots, biases, and fallacies we are all prone to. Even though
we are not the rational economic actors that economists since Adam
Smith believed we are, all is not lost. Irrational we may be, but our
irrationality is not random, it falls into discernible patterns that
we as individuals can be aware of, and empowered by the revelations
of behavioral economics—and with practice and self-discipline—we
can learn to make better economic
and financial decisions and choices.
Next
time, as promised, we will segue to the field of moral psychology and
see how our moral reasoning can go awry.
Works Cited
1. Ariely,
D. ‘Ch. 1-The Truth about Relativity’ Predict. Irrational.
p.10; (Harper: New York, NY, 2008).
2. Ariely,
D. & Levav, J. ‘Sequential Choice in Group Settings: Taking the
Road Less Traveled and Less Enjoyed’ J.
Consum. Res.
27,
p.279–290; (Dec. 2000). at
<http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=keh&AN=3938690&site=ehost-live>23
Jun. 2017
3.
‘Hanlon’s Razor’ Wikipedia.
(27 Apr. 2017). at
<https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Hanlon%27s_razor&oldid=777543724>27
Jun. 2017
Endnotes
i Individuals’ “need for uniqueness” is a well-validated aspect of human psychology (see: https://www.google.com/webhp?hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwjh_sazrd7UAhXJ4IMKHVSeA8QQPAgD#hl=en&q=need+for+uniqueness+theory&spf=1498578169874). The scenario of a woman being distressed at the thought of showing up to a party in the same dress as someone else may be more than a mere comedic cliché.
ii http://www.sjdm.org/dmidi/Consumers%27_Need_for_Uniqueness.html
iii Apparently, the hyphenated word “consumer–citizens” raises the hackles of some folks, but the reason I decided to go with it is that so often, the same biases, fallacies, and blind spots that affect our behavior as consumers are the same ones that influence our politics. A question that has arisen in the last 35 or so years that illustrates this commonality of the two spheres of modern life is: “Why so many working-class, less well-off folks vote Republican, against their own economic self-interest?”
iv See: https://books.google.com/books?id=IeRWCgAAQBAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=isbn:9781583671610&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwiKi-z4ttTUAhWs5YMKHY-GB8QQ6AEIJjAA#v=onepage&q=greatest%20concerted%20attempt&f=false, p.276-7
Initially started at https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Criticism_of_advertising#Influence, then look for Robert McChesney.
Comments